Excessive leverage was a primary cause of the financial crisis, and yet big banks and even some government
Large banks say the risk-insensitive nature of the Basel III Supplemental Leverage Ratio (SLR) restricts market liquidity by increasing banks’ cost of holding so-called safe securities and derivatives for market-making activities. A proposed change to the leverage ratio would remove those assets from the SLR calculation. But the proposed change would allow more leverage which could amplify the alleged liquidity problem.
The Basel III SLR regulation, finalized in 2014, put a limit on large banking organization leverage by requiring banking organizations with over $250 billion in assets to meet a new capital threshold that treats all holdings with an equal risk weighting. The SLR requirement must be met in addition to banks’ risk-based capital requirements. The
The SLR is the ratio of an institution’s Tier 1 capital to its “total leverage exposure.” Total leverage exposure equals a holding company’s consolidated assets plus exposures from derivatives, repurchase agreements, securities lending, lines of credit, guarantees and other off-balance activities that contributed to the excessive leverage that imperiled many institutions in the recent financial crisis. All eight G-SIBs currently meet the 5% minimum SLR, but many of them could not satisfy the requirement in the most recent Federal Reserve stress test.
The case for relaxing the SLR has been championed by
The recent Treasury Department
Using regulatory data, my estimates suggest that these changes could increase the SLR reported by some G-SIBs by more than 1.5 percentage points — or the equivalent of gaining roughly $40 billion in new Tier 1 capital — just by making a few “minor” technical changes to the SLR calculation.
Make no mistake, the Treasury’s proposed SLR rule change would allow G-SIBs to increase their leverage. And this is why the large banks’ argument in favor of changing the SLR is so thin.
Typically, the cost — and therefore the profitability — of an investment does not depend on how it is financed. This was the finding of the Nobel Prize-winning economists Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller in their famous
Duffie’s article for The Clearing House argues that the distortion inhibiting G-SIBs from providing liquidity is the so-called debt overhang problem. Put simply, debt overhang occurs when a company has so much outstanding debt that it alters bank incentives so that management only approves investments that will not reduce the risk of its future profit stream. Profitable but safe investments will be rejected because the profits from these investments are more likely to be used to pay off debt holder claims than to yield shareholders a dividend or capital gain.
Here lies the Achilles' heel of the Clearing House argument. If the debt overhang problem is the cause of diminished G-SIB participation in safe market-making and derivatives activities, then how can the correct solution be to replace the current SLR with a risk-weighted SLR requirement that allows G-SIBs to increase their leverage? Higher G-SIB leverage will only make the debt overhang problem worse, not better. The Treasury’s proposed changes to the SLR calculation will not restore the incentive for banks to get back into safe market-making activities.
If a debt overhang problem is really causing G-SIBs to reduce their participation in providing “safe” liquidity, the solution is not to replace the SLR; the solution is to reduce the debt overhang problem by reducing G-SIB leverage.