Has policy schizophrenia gripped the Federal Reserve? Some people
Over the last 24 months, the U.S. central bank has been gradually raising its interest rate target as labor markets tightened, putting upward pressure on prices and wages. At the same time, the Fed has
Interest rate increases tighten financial conditions. Regulatory relief loosens them. This leaves many people wondering whether the Fed is working at cross-purposes: reducing credit supply via the monetary channel, while boosting it through regulatory relief. Some even worry that the two actions combined could increase financial fragility, spelling disaster akin to 2008.
While it’s true that monetary tightening and deregulation — however modest — counteract each other, fears that the Fed’s actions will compromise the safety of the financial system are overblown.
Start with monetary policy. The mission of the Fed is to promote full employment and maintain stable prices. With joblessness at
Raising the cost of credit will, in general, reduce credit demand. Higher interest rates will therefore reduce loan volumes. In this way, consumer demand and therefore inflationary pressures will be tamed.
But that doesn’t mean that banks will suffer. They lend funds at a higher interest rate than the one paid to depositors. The difference between the two, the net interest margin, is a measure of bank profitability. Lower interest rates have
Indeed, Fed researchers
So, while overall loan volumes may decline as interest rates rise, bank profits from each loan could actually increase.
Moreover, bank profitability shouldn’t in and of itself concern policymakers. However, the ability of financial institutions to yield an adequate rate of return makes failure less likely and, to the extent that interest rates affect all banks, it also makes the financial system less fragile. Higher interest rates, in the present context, do not herald financial catastrophe but rather a return to the historical norm.
Critics of deregulation claim that the Fed’s moves in that direction might restore another, less auspicious, historical norm — namely, the pre-crisis environment of undercapitalized financial institutions. They say proposals to adjust bank leverage ratios in line with the individual characteristics of each bank amount to a giveaway to the biggest institutions, for which taxpayers might ultimately be liable.
The criticism is disproportionate. The Fed
One may quibble with the specific changes proposed, but to posit that this amounts to a wholesale gutting of the post-crisis regulatory regime is simply misleading.
That said, the status quo is hardly optimal, either. As mentioned, new bank creation has ground to a halt since 2008. Banks, especially those with assets under $1 billion,
The modest moves at regulatory relief over the last year and a half should be viewed in this context. Policymakers on both sides of the aisle have been
Regulatory relief can facilitate lending and lower barriers to competition, both eminently desirable goals so long as the costs of lending decisions are borne by the banks and their customers, not taxpayers. Furthermore, it would be a mistake to infer from the sheer scale and complexity of Dodd-Frank that it is in fact effective at achieving its goals of safety and soundness. If anything, complexity of regulation has historically been a driver of financial instability.
While there is much good to be had from simpler, less burdensome financial regulation, the Fed’s proposed reforms make precious little headway in that direction. But neither do they compromise the integrity of the financial system. To suggest otherwise is to make a beneficial policy change more difficult and to divert policymakers’ attention from genuine sources of systemic risk.