Kate Berry's
In those days, there was no such thing as "asset-liability management" and no financial institutions were required (or chose) to write down a "liquidity management policy." By the time commercial banks and credit unions were permitted to join the system in 1989, the management and boards of directors of depository institutions, with the encouragement of their respective regulatory agencies, all had a strong focus on asset-liability and liquidity management, guided by written, board-approved policies.
Today, all depository institutions are required by their respective regulators to identify "contingent sources of liquidity" in their policies. These funds are expected to be available to address any shortfalls caused by what economists call "liquidity shocks." The sources of liquidity shocks are unanticipated declines in deposits or unexpected increases in loan demand. One method to address these liquidity shortfalls is to borrow the needed funds in the capital markets. But more than 90% of depository institutions lack access to the capital markets as a result of a so-called "market imperfection." Because of large fixed costs associated with issuing securities, intermediaries in the capital markets will only underwrite securities in large amounts.
The classic assumption in economic analysis of free, unfettered access to markets consequently does not hold for small financial institutions facing the capital markets. But through the Federal Home Loan Bank System's Office of Finance, the Home Loan banks can borrow in the capital markets in large sums. Having accessed the market, the banks, in turn, can lend these funds to member institutions in smaller amounts. By acting as a classic financial intermediary, the Home Loan banks solve the market imperfection problem. Not surprisingly, almost all community-oriented institutions identify Home Loan bank borrowings (known as "advances") as a primary source of contingent liquidity in their policies. When the system was created over 90 years ago, the concept of "capital market imperfections" was as foreign to financial institution managers as asset-liability and liquidity management were.
Since a small number of very large financial institutions can access the capital markets, it might be argued they should not be permitted to be members of the Home Loan Bank System. But these institutions were not excluded in the enabling legislation. Today, they are large users of advances and hence underwrite a substantial portion of the infrastructure costs of operating the system. Excluding these large institutions would consequently force consolidation in the system and substantially shrink both its assets and its earnings. The drop in earnings would yield a concomitant decline in the system's contribution to affordable housing.
Some have suggested that the FHFA should seek to require the Home Loan banks to lend only to support housing-related lending. But tying advances to explicit funding of home finance will increase prospective liquidity risk in the banking system by short-circuiting access to advances for addressing liquidity shortfalls on the liability side of the balance sheet. Lenders would then be forced to decline requests for loans, including housing-related loans.
It would seem to be counterproductive for the FHFA to implement regulations or support legislation that could reduce funds available for affordable housing and increase potential liquidity risk in the financial system. Significant evolution and innovation are hallmarks of the financial system since the 1930s and we should not be surprised to see that the Home Loan Bank System has evolved along with it.